Слике страница
PDF
ePub

227 as the tonnage of lumber shipped over their lines and their revenue therefrom have steadily grown in amount. Take the two years, 1901 and 1902, immediately preceding the present advanced rate, and 1903 the year of the advance; the lumber tonnage of defendants has grown in those years from 6,566,407 tons in 1901, to 9,808,463 tons in 1903, an increase of 3,242,056 tons. (Finding 9.) The business of the defendants, not only in lumber, but in traffic in general, has grown and is growing largely, and in view of the fact, that they derive their franchises, or "right to exist" from the public, the lumber shippers, as part of the public, might plausibly, to say the least, claim that they have a right to participate in the prosperity of the defendants by having their rate reduced rather than advanced. The general rule is, the greater the tonnage of an article transported, the lower should be the rate. No rule is more firmly grounded in reason or more universally recognized by carriers. It is because of the greater density of traffic north of the Ohio River in Central Freight Association Territory and in the Eastern Territory that rates in general are made materially lower in those territories than in Southern Territory....

As before stated, the advance in the rate is not sought to be justified on the ground that the rate in force was unremunera

tive or not a reasonable return for the service rendered. The prin- 2nd frount cipal ground urged is that additional revenue was needed to meet increased expenses and that, in the language of one of the principal witnesses for the defendant, they "looked around to see where they could best get that additional revenue and one of the commodities which they thought would bear the advance was lumber." Carriers have no right to advance a rate which is already rea- public as sonably high and which yields an adequate return for the service as stuckwell as rendered, solely because additional revenue is needed. In Smyth v. Ames (169 U. S. 547, 42 L. ed. 849, 18 Sup. Ct. Rep. 418), the holders are to Supreme Court held that "the public is entitled to demand that be considered no more be exacted from it for the use of a public highway than the services rendered by it are reasonably worth." . . . "It cannot therefore be admitted that a railroad corporation maintaining a highway under the authority of a state may fix its rates with a view solely to its own interests and ignore the rights of the public." In Covington & Lexington Turnpike Road Co. v. Sandford (164 U. S. 596, 597, 41 L. ed. 566, 17 Sup. Ct. Rep. 198), it is said: A corporation "is not entitled, as of right and without reference to the interests of the public, to realize a given per cent. upon its capital stock. . . . Stockholders are not the only persons whose rights or interests are to be considered. The rights of the public

[graphic]

are not to be ignored. . . . The public cannot properly be subjected to unreasonable rates in order simply that stockholders may earn dividends."

It is clear, therefore, that the mere fact of the need of additional revenue to meet increased expense does not justify the advance in the rate on lumber.2 . . .

Facts.

SAVAGE, J. IN BRUNSWICK AND TOPSHAM WATER
DISTRICT v. MAINE WATER CO.

99 Me. 371. 1904.1

We turn to the other question involved in this request. That relates to the assumed existence of a nearer and cheaper source of supply than the one now in use by the company, which is a part of its present entire plant, and which in part represents its actual investment. We do not doubt that, when the worth of a public service of this kind to the public or the customers is spoken of, necessarily one of the elements to be considered is the expense at which the public or customers, as a community, might serve themselves were they free to do so, and were it not for the existence of the practically exclusive franchises of the supplying company. When the worth of the water to a consumer is estimated, we are not limited to the value of water itself, for it is an absolute necessity. Its value has no limit. Water, speaking abstractly, is priceless; it is inestimable. To sustain life it must be had at any price. And in this respect a public water service differs from all other kinds of public service. In estimating what it is reasonable to charge for a water service, that is, not exceeding its worth to the consumers, water is to be regarded as a product, and the cost at which it can be produced or distributed is an important element of its worth. It is not the only element, however. The individuals of a community may with reason prefer to pay rates which yield a return to the money of other people higher than the event shows they could serve themselves for, rather than make the venture themselves, and risk their own money to lose in an uncertain enterprise. It was said by us in the Waterville case that the investor is entitled to something for the risk he takes, and it is not unreasonable for the consumer to be charged with 2. something on that account. That is one of the things which make up the worth of the water to the customer. The same element enters

Text

2 For a full history of this case see, also, 123 Fed. 789, 138 Fed. 753, 148 Fed. 1021, and 206 U. S. 428.

1 Only one point is reprinted from the opinion.- ED.

always into the relations between producer and consumer.
such a consideration as this last one must always be treated with
caution. The company is only entitled to fair returns, in any
event, and "fair" to the customer as well as to itself.

In the aspect now being considered, the worth of a water serviee to its customers does not mean what it would cost some one individual, or some few individuals, to supply themselves, for one may be blessed with a spring, and another may have a good well. It means the worth to the individuals in a community taken as a whole. It is the worth to the customers as individuals, but as individuals making up a community of water takers. In the very nature of things, a water system is usually intended to supply a somewhat compactly settled community, or a community whose geographical limits are somewhat restricted. As a matter of fact, in this state such systems usually supply villages, or the more compact portions of cities. The necessity does not exist for extending such systems beyond these limits, and the expense would be practically prohibitive. Such a community must, in general, stand as a whole. The rates for such a system are generally and properly uniform, although the expense of supplying some, as those nearer the source of supply, is actually less than that of supplying those at the outermost limits. Still the benefits are uniform, and uniform rates are rea sonable. Now, such a community is, we think, entitled to the benefit of such natural and sufficient facilities for procuring pure water as exist in its vicinity. Communities are in every respect entitled to the benefit of existing natural advantages.

[merged small][ocr errors]

5

It therefore seems to be reasonable that a public water service company undertaking to supply a community with water is bound to do so wisely and economically. It is bound to take advantage of practicable natural facilities. If there is more than one source of supply, other things being equal, the community is entitled to have the least expensive one used. So long as the company enjoys. practically exclusive franchises, so long it must afford the community the benefit of the conditions which nature has provided for 5. them. For instance, if water can profitably be served from a nearer source of supply at a certain rate, the company ought not to be permitted to charge a higher rate based upon the expense of bringing it from a farther and more expensive souree. And this even if in attempting to serve this and other communities together it might be more profitable to the company to do so.2

2 As to the burden of proof when a public utility raises its rates see People er rel. New York Cent. & H. R. R. Co. v. Public Serv. Comm. (1915), 215 N. Y. 241. Cf. People ex rel. New York Teleph. Co. v. Public Serv. Comm. (N. Y., 1915), 169 App. Div. 448.

CONTRACT RATES.

"We can have no doubt that under the authority of the laws referred to and in view of the terms of the ordinances in question and the acceptances by the grantees the City of Columbus made valid and binding contracts with the Companies, binding for the term of twenty-five years. By these contracts, obligatory alike upon the City and the Company, the City granted the right to use the streets and the Company bound itself to furnish the contemplated service at the rates fixed in the ordinances. . . . The Company seeks now by its own action to terminate the contracts, still binding upon it by their terms as to rates of fare to be charged, and seeks to have the aid of a court of equity by enjoining the City from any further requirement of service under them. . . It may be, and taking the allegations of the bill to be true, it undoubtedly is, a case of a hard bargain. But equity does not relieve from hard bargains simply beeause they are such. It may be that the efficiency of the service and fairness in dealing with the company which performs such important and necessary service ought to require an advance in rates; such was the strongly announced opinion of the War Labor Board. But these and kindred considerations address themselves to the duly constituted authorities having the control of the subject-matter." Columbus Ry., P. & L. Co. v. Columbus (1919), 249 U. S. 399, 409, 410. 414. See Notes, 6 A. L. R. 1659; 19 Columbia L. Rev. 144; 32 Harvard L. Rev. 74. The right of the State to abrogate franchise rates and rate contracts made with patrons is dealt with in section 3 of this chapter.

Section 2.

THE POWER OF THE STATE TO FIX RATES: DELEGATION OF POWER TO COMMISSIONS.

CHICAGO, BURLINGTON AND QUINCY RAILROAD CO. v. IOWA.

94 U. S. 155. 1876.1

APPEAL from the Circuit Court of the United States for the District of Iowa.

This bill was filed by the Chicago, Burlington, and Quincy Railroad Company, a corporation created by the laws of Illinois, for an injunction restraining the Attorney-General of the State of Iowa from prosecuting suits against it or its officers, under the provisions of an act passed by the legislature of Iowa, entitled "An Act to establish reasonable maximum rates of charges for the transportation of freight and passengers on the different railroads of this State," approved March 23, 1874. . . .

1 Part of the statement of facts, the arguments of counsel and part of the opinion are omitted.- ED.

MR. CHIEF JUSTICE WAITE delivered the opinion of the court. Railroad companies are carriers for hire. They are incorporated as such, and given extraordinary powers, in order that they may the better serve the public in that capacity. They are, therefore, engaged in a public employment affecting the public interest, and, under the decision in Munn v. Illinois, supra, p. 113, subject to legislative control as to their rates of fare and freight, unless pro tected by their charters.

The Burlington and Missouri River Railroad Company, the benefit of whose charter the Chicago, Burlington, and Quincy Railroad Company now claims, was organized under the general corporation law of Iowa, with power to contract, in reference to its business, the same as private individuals, and to establish by-laws and make all rules and regulations deemed expedient in relation to its affairs, but being subject, nevertheless, at all times to such rules and regulations as the general assembly of Iowa might from time to time enact and provide. This is, in substance, its charter, and to that extent it is protected as by a contract; for it is now too late to contend that the charter of a corporation is not a contract within the meaning of that clause in the Constitution of the United States which prohibits a State from passing any law impairing the obligation of a contract. Whatever is granted is secured subject only to the limitations and reservations in the charter or in the law or constitutions which govern it.

This company, in the transactions of its business, has the same rights, and is subject to the same control, as private individuals under the same circumstances. It must carry when called upon to do so, and can charge only a reasonable sum for the carriage. In the absence of any legislative regulation upon the subject, the courts must decide for it, as they do for private persons, when controversies arise, what is reasonable. But when the legislature steps in and prescribes a maximum of charge, it operates upon this corporation the same as it does upon individuals engaged in a similar business. It was within the power of the company to call upon the legislature to fix permanently this limit, and make it a part of the charter; and, if it was refused, to abstain from building the road and establishing the contemplated business. If that had been done, the charter might have presented a contract against future legislative interference. But it was not; and the company invested its capital, relying upon the good faith of the people and the wisdom and impartiality of legislators for protection against wrong under the form of legislative regulation.

It is a matter of no importance that the power of regulation now under consideration was not exercised for more than twenty years

[ocr errors]
« ПретходнаНастави »